Sneha Girap (Editor)

Axel Leijonhufvud

Updated on
Edit
Like
Comment
Share on FacebookTweet on TwitterShare on LinkedInShare on Reddit
Nationality
  
Swedish

Influenced
  
Yanis Varoufakis

Role
  
Economist

Name
  
Axel Leijonhufvud


Axel Leijonhufvud austrianeconomiststypepadcoma6a00d83451eb0069

Born
  
1933
Stockholm, Sweden

Institution
  
University of TrentoUCLABrookings Institution

Alma mater
  
Lund UniversityUniversity of PittsburghNorthwestern University

Influences
  
Leon Walras, John Maynard Keynes

Influenced by
  
Leon Walras, John Maynard Keynes

Books
  
Keynes and the Classics, Macroeconomic instability and coor, High Inflation: The Arne, On Keynesian economic, Information and coordination

School or tradition
  
Neoclassical economics

Axel leijonhufvud debt inflation and austerity 4 5


Axel Leijonhufvud (born 1933) is a Swedish economist, currently professor emeritus at the University of California Los Angeles (UCLA) and professor at the University of Trento, Italy.

Contents

Axel Leijonhufvud wwwineteconomicsorguploadspressphotosaxelpr

Friedrich von hayek and axel leijonhufvud nov 1978


Academic career

He obtained his bachelor's degree at the University of Lund, earned an MA in Economics from the University of Pittsburgh and a Ph.D. in Economics from Northwestern University in 1967. He accepted a position as Acting Assistant Professor in the Economics Department at UCLA in 1964, was promoted to Associate Professor in 1967, and to Full Professor in 1971. In 1991, he started the Center for Computable Economics at UCLA and remained its Director until 1997. Leijonhufvud was awarded an honoris causa doctoral degree by the University of Lund in 1983 and by the University Nice - Sophia Antipolis in 1996. In 1995 Leijonhufvud was appointed Professor of Monetary Theory and Policy at the University of Trento in Italy, where he is also part of the CEEL (Computable and Experimental Economics Laboratory).

Economic theory

In 1968 he published a famous scholarly book entitled On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes. Leijonhufvud's monetary economics vitally depended on the earlier work of his friend and mentor, the American economist Robert W. Clower.

In the book, Leijonhufvud argued that John Hicks' IS/LM (Investment—Saving / Liquidity preference—Money supply) formulation of Keynes General Theory was inadequate as an explanation for the "involuntary unemployment" in John Maynard Keynes's writings. Rather, Leijonhufvud's reading of Keynes emphasizes disequilibrium phenomena, which can't be addressed in the IS/LM framework, as central to Keynes explanation of unemployment and economic depression. Leijonhufvud used this observation as a point of departure to advocate a "cybernetic" approach to macroeconomics where the algorithm by which prices and quantities adjust is explicitly specified allowing the dynamic economy to be studied without imposing the standard Walrasian equilibrium concept. In particular, Leijonhufvud advocated formally modelling the process by which information moves through the economy. While the "cybernetic" approach may have failed to gain traction in mainstream economics, it presaged the rational expectations revolution that would ultimately supplant the IS/LM model as the dominant paradigm in academic macroeconomics.

Leijonhufvud wrote also the article "The Wicksell Connection: Variation on a Theme", where he presents the Z-Theory. In another article called "Effective Demand Failures", he presents the Corridor Hypothesis.

In 2006 the Economics Department at UCLA organized a conference in honor of Axel Leijonhufvud's contributions to the department and to economics at large. Lars Peter Hansen, Peter Howitt, David K. Levine, Edmund S. Phelps, Thomas J. Sargent, and Kenneth L. Sokoloff were among the contributors to this conference.

Life Among the Econ

Published in the Western Economic Journal in 1973, Axel Leijonhufvud’s Life Among the Econ is a comical article outlining the discipline of economics, and the scholars that practice it, from the perspective of an anthropologist. Professional economists are treated as a tribe known as “the Econ” and ensuing tribal analogues are produced throughout the piece to characterize the group’s unusual behavior.

While describing the “caste and status” structure of “the Econ”, Leijonhufvud remarks how “status relationships do not seem to form a simple hierarchical ‘pecking order’”…and that “in societies with a traditional pecking-order…an equilibrium develops in which little actual pecking ever takes place”. By these comical observations Leijonhufvud’s point is that within academic economics, there is little respect given on behalf of young economists toward their experienced colleagues. Or, if there is such a recognized hierarchy, it is so stringent that little mobility is allowed—those at the top of the academic ladder don’t easily give in to the desires of their lower-ranking counterparts, a practice that “carries no formal sanctions.” At the time of writing, Leijonhufvud had solely worked for UCLA, so perhaps this commentary is uniquely directed toward his fellow bruins (highly unlikely...).

In any case, Leijonhufvud later writes that hierarchy not only emerges generationally, but also between various fields of research, “A comparison of status relationships in the different ‘fields’ shows a definite common pattern.” For “the Econ”, the relative respect given to varying fields—the word they usurp for what we commonly understand as a caste—is contingent on their use of “modls”, referring to the development of various economic models existing in academia today. Moreover, “modls” produced by different fields are not equally acknowledged by all—Macro and Micro Econs hardly appreciate, or even understand, the “modls” produced by the other. Within this allegorical language it’s hard to miss Leijonhufvud’s point that there is little interdepartmental understanding and collaboration in economics, at least during the early 1970s. Like common cultural misunderstandings, these gaps allow members of various schools of thought to quickly denigrate members of competing schools without first recognizing the context in which those schools, or “fields” as Leijonhufvud aligns them with, operate.

Returning to his earlier critique of the generational pecking-order, Leijonhufvud further develops his theory of “grads, adults and elders”. For “the Econ”, the young adult, or “grad”, is not accepted into the community until he produces a “modl” of sufficient complication for the master he or she works under. Yet, this rite of initiation does not end with one initial acceptance—in order to maintain one’s membership one needs to continually produce “modls”, lest you be “turned out of the ‘dept’ to perish in the wilderness”. This cultural demonstration is, of course, Leijonhufvud’s commentary on the incessant need to publish new economic models within academia to sustain one’s faculty position in an economic department. And yet, ironically, Leijonhufvud will later note that these models rarely apply to the real world, though they are still the basis by which “Econs” look down upon Sociogs and Polscis (sociologists and political scientists). In defense of this practice among “the Econ”, Leijonhufvud argues that it actually doesn’t matter much whether “modls” work (“the Implementarist issue is no longer seen as productive”) so long as they are filled with significant beliefs (this practice is particularly present among the “Math-econ”, the priests of “the Econ”).

Leijonhufvud ends his comical caricature by recognizing that, because of the aforementioned practices surrounding ineffectiveness of “modls”, “The prospect for the Econ is bleak.” While they are growing at increasing rates, most of them are quite poor and not self-sustainable. And yet, “the Econ remain as of old a proud and warlike race”, which is all to say that economics as a primary discipline among the social sciences is dwindling even though members of its community do not want to recognize it as such. Sure, “the Econ” had inspiring routes, but they have since exhausted their resources and trust with those on the outside and collapse from within has already begun—more and more “Econs” are reduced to vagabonds with no true community to call home.

Taken as a whole, the piece is a humorous read for anyone interested in the study or history of economics, particularly for those just about to enter graduate school in the field. Only time will tell if Leijonhufvud’s pessimistic predictions come true.

References

Axel Leijonhufvud Wikipedia