Puneet Varma (Editor)

Neomercantilism

Updated on
Edit
Like
Comment
Share on FacebookTweet on TwitterShare on LinkedInShare on Reddit

Neomercantilism is an economically nationalist trade policy regime based on classical mercantilism. It is predicated on the notion that what naturally evolves, and survives the test of time, is inherently robust and practically beneficial: what has worked, will work. It is observed that mercantile policies have been employed since at least the 1300s in England under King Edward III, and 1250s in Venice, and continued in various forms until the era of decolonization in the middle of the twentieth century. During this time they were the policy choices that were active, and likely contributed to the Dutch Golden Age and Britain's Industrial Revolution.

Contents

As in classical mercantilism, neomercantilism is concerned with enriching and empowering the nation, and the state, to the maximum possible degree. This is done by acquiring and retaining as much economic activity within the nation's borders as possible. Of particular importance are ensuring economic independence in manufacturing and advanced industries, or those with military or national security applications (such as food or energy supplies). Achieving economic autarky is an element of neomercantilism.

This is done through encouraging exports of technologically advanced or manufactured products, while encouraging the import of raw materials. This is designed to artificially elevate the nation's production by producing both for their own, and their trading partner's consumption. This maintains artificially high employment and economic activity, which reduces the welfare burden on government. Theoretically, it aims to provide high economic growth with a small government and low tax obligations.

Rise of mercantilism

As feudalism became incapable of regulating the new methods of production and distribution, mercantilism emerged as a system for managing economic growth through international trade. It was a form of merchant capitalism relying on protectionism. It was developed in the sixteenth century by the European nation-states to enrich their own countries by encouraging exports and limiting imports. In modern terms, the intention was to achieve a "favorable" balance of trade.

Example

The East India Company is one of the best examples of the collaboration of state and merchants in exploiting market opportunities. The benefits that occurred as a result were:

  • it slowly encouraged the evolution of regional into nation states;
  • a commercial class emerged which, in return for paying taxes, received state protection in the form of monopolies and tariffs;
  • once colonies were established, managing the transport of private goods and the volume of trade enriched the imperialist states and provided both significant employment for the general population and opportunities for upward class mobility for the more enterprising individuals.
  • Early criticism

    In The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith criticised the implicit political corruption of mercantilism in limiting the benefits of trade to the elite classes, and asserted that free trade should benefit all interested parties. Smith considered mercantilism a system where one country increases its power by getting excess gold on foreign transactions and it is a system created by merchants in order to get monopolies and easy profits.

    Some people believe that, because Britain adopted his call for free trade policies, it fell behind the United States and Germany by 1880, having gained its dominance under the mercantilism of Cromwell and Elizabeth I (when according to Adam Smith, England was less mercantilist than Spain and Portugal, who decayed much due to their colonial mercantilist policies. The success of the United States and Germany drove the reintroduction of protectionist regulations in the rest of Europe.

    Philosophical framework

    Neomercantilism is founded on the classical conservative principle that what has worked in the past will likely work in the future, which was coherently articulated by British statesman Edmund Burke regarding political constitutions and the French Revolution. More recently, Nassim Nicholas Taleb's observations on robustness and fragility have been used to theoretically justify neomercantile ideas: what evolved did so by conferring benefits, mercantilism evolved naturally (as opposed to theories such as free trade based on comparative advantage, or communism, which were theory-first philosophies), and therefore likely confers benefits. There is an element of conservative historicism underpinning the system.

    Central tenets

    Neomercantilism combines the central tenets of: (1) economic protectionism with the added caveat that (2) trade deals should be actively sought out, on the condition that they asymmetrically benefit the proposing nation over the other.

    1. Protectionist elements include: the protection of domestic producers by discouraging value-added imports through tariffs, structural barriers to prevent entry of foreign companies into domestic markets, manipulation of the currency value against foreign currencies to encourage exports and foreign direct investment inflows, and limitations on foreign ownership of domestic corporations. While all nations engage in these activities to some degree, neomercantilism makes them the focus of economic policy.
    2. Trade deals: Trade deals are actively sought out by neomercantilist states, on the condition that they asymmetrically benefit the proposing state. Neomercantilist regimes are not interested in free or fair trade, they want what is sometimes described as "predatory" trade. Ideally, one nation will export advanced, and manufactured, products, in exchange for raw materials or exotic products that they are unable to produce. The paradigm is illustrated perfectly with reference to Britain's colonial trade: Britain exported manufactured products to the Caribbean colonies, who exchanged sugar, which Britain could not produce. This artificially increased Britain's industrial output and demand for labor, while at the same time ensuring the Caribbean remained dependent upon British imports. This paradigm is sometimes referred to as import dependency.

    This use of protectionism is criticized on grounds that go back to Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations, which was aimed directly at classical mercantilist policies, and whose arguments are applied to neo-mercantilism. Namely that protectionism is effective as a means of fostering economic independence and national stability; and questioning the conclusion that it allows for sustainable development of the nation's industrial base in the most efficient manner. Instead market economics has for over two centuries argued that increasing competition within the nation which will more effectively promote capital development and efficient allocation of resources. "Free traders" argue that by closing an economy, resources will be spent duplicating products that could more effectively be bought from abroad, and that there will be less development of exports which offer a comparative advantage. Market economists also argue that protection denies a nation's own consumers the opportunity to buy at cheaper market prices when quotas or tariffs are imposed on imports.

    The subsidy of goods has also been advocated under neomercantilism. The fair trade movement claims that the protection of stability in emerging economies by guaranteeing a minimum purchase of goods at prices above those available in the current world markets, can contribute to restoring economic and social balance as well as promote social justice. Proponents of the movement argue that this may help to avoid the instability generated by the influence of global corporations on developed and developing nations.

    Neomercantilists claim that "free trade" results in a negative philosophy that a nation that is not competitive deserves to decline and perish, just like an under-performing corporation should. They argue that "free trade" does not work well whenever dumping is practiced or the international rules do not take into account the differences between wages, costs environmental regulations, and benefits from nation to nation. For instance, there is a major difference in the cost of labour between a "First World" and "Third World" country for two equally skilled (or unskilled) sets of workers. When this economic reality is exploited by "First World" manufacturers, the benefits accrue to "First World" shareholders and consumers (and slightly improved work condition of exploited Third World workers) at the expense of privileged "First World" workers and their status in the "middle class".

    An unquestioningly open policy in such circumstances may effectively devalue "first world" human capital investments in favor of financial capital investments. Consider for example, a person deciding whether to invest in training as an engineer or in a portfolio of financial assets. Offshoring dramatically increases the effective supply of engineers, and as a result, their price will tend to decline (or grow at a slower rate). This decline will be increased by the lower cost of living in non-first world countries that would allow an engineer there to live much better on a lower nominal salary than their first world counterpart (see purchasing power parity). This obviously is resulting in a huge immigration of skilled professionals from first world countries to the third world, seeking a better quality of life.

    Faced with such prospects, rational economic agents will tend to avoid investing in human capital in areas that are vulnerable to such government-induced devaluation. Instead, they will shift training toward areas that are "protected by regulation" (for example: careers in law, medicine, government) or social tradition (tenured academia), or socio-cultural factors (sales) or local physical requirements (nursing, medicine, construction). Alternatively, rational economic agents in "first world" economies may choose to invest in financial assets instead of human capital—further eroding the long term ability of the "first world" country to produce and grow. As predicted by Adam Smith, this effect would reduce the inequality between First World and Third World countries, increasing overall fairness.

    Additionally, since cost of goods sold tends to be a larger component of total revenue than profits for most industries, production within a country may keep a larger portion of the total wealth within the local economy in comparison to dividends of profits and reduced prices on consumer goods. Furthermore, infrastructure investments may be reduced when production is shifted offshore. Over the longer term, such reduced local investments may reduce longer term productivity and economic growth. Neomercantilist economies on the other hand are often characterised by "higher long term growth rates" (that tend to flatten when neomercantilist policies are halted). This claim unfortunately is not verified among developed nations, where Australia is both the main proponent of international free trade and among the first world countries, the one with the higher sustained growth during the last fifteen years. Anecdotally, as of February 2009 Australia was the only developed country who was not officially in recession.

    The language of neomercantilist policies repeats the claims of earlier centuries that protective measures benefit the nation as a whole and that governmental intervention secures the "wealth of the nation" for future generations. In doing so, neomercantilist admit that the interests of large corporations might as often be represented and protected as pushed aside for the national interest.

    As a neomercantilist nation's industrial production capacity and improving research and development grow as a threat to the hegemon's (who usually unilaterally practices free-trade as Britain in the 19th century and the US in the late 20th century) domestic markets, so protectionism is the usual response, initially through political and, when necessary, military means (see World War I).

    United States and Germany in 19th century

    By 1880 the United States passed the British Empire in economic strength—ahead of Germany, second in strength, due to Bismarck's adherence to similar neomercantilist policies.

    After 1900, Britain was unable to remain an effective hegemon, having followed its "free trade" philosophy since the 1840s, but the United States was still pursuing policies of its American School rooted in Hamilton's three reports, that it had embraced in the 1860s under Abraham Lincoln. Germany followed Otto von Bismarck's policies based on Friedrich List's "National System", and American economic practices—allowing both powers to continue their dominance in world economics and power. Germany chose to use its strength to pursue a 'balance of power' with the British Empire leading indirectly to World War I, whereas the United States refrained from European power struggles through its foreign policy of 'isolationism' or non-interventionism in foreign conflicts.

    Criticism

    Classic liberal economic theory states that free trade, sound money, and prosperity are mutually interdependent parts of a single economic policy but, when inflation intruded into the world trade system, protectionism followed.

    In Two Hegemonies, Pigman describes a hegemon's principal function as, "...underwriting a liberal international trading system that is beneficial to the hegemon but, paradoxically, even more beneficial to its potential rivals." As it grows in significance, the hegemon expands its sphere of influence to include interests that have to be promoted through liberal economic policies. During this period, the hegemon will benefit directly from the increased international trade. But other economies also prosper. They are not burdened with high defence spending and the costs associated with overseas development, though these costs may be balanced or outweighed by the international domination of markets and resources. The "hegemon's dilemma" is whether to revert to neomercantilist policies if its hegemony is threatened, or to continue free trade and risk a relative decline.

    Game theory analysis – trade policy as iterated prisoner's dilemma

    Trade policy is perhaps best viewed economically as an ongoing "iterated / repeated" prisoner's dilemma game.

    The prisoner's dilemma is not a zero-sum game. Everyone would be better off if all players cooperated than if they defected. (Mutual cooperation is a Pareto improvement over mutual defection.) Unfortunately, each player has an incentive to defect against their opponent. By defecting a player can defend themselves against an opponent's defection, and can exploit a cooperating opponent. In single-shot prisoner's dilemma, the economically dominant action is to defect.

    However, trade policy is formed over time—and is better modelled by iterated /repeated prisoner's dilemma. Key early work in this area includes research by David Kreps, and by Robert Axelrod. One of the most important developments in game theory is the development of the folk theorem when applied to iterated prisoner's dilemma games.

    References

    Neomercantilism Wikipedia