Puneet Varma (Editor)

Comonotonicity

Updated on
Edit
Like
Comment
Share on FacebookTweet on TwitterShare on LinkedInShare on Reddit

In probability theory, comonotonicity mainly refers to the perfect positive dependence between the components of a random vector, essentially saying that they can be represented as increasing functions of a single random variable. In two dimensions it is also possible to consider perfect negative dependence, which is called countermonotonicity.

Contents

Comonotonicity is also related to the comonotonic additivity of the Choquet integral.

The concept of comonotonicity has applications in financial risk management and actuarial science, see e.g. Dhaene et al. (2002a) and Dhaene et al. (2002b). In particular, the sum of the components X1 + X2 + · · · + Xn is the riskiest if the joint probability distribution of the random vector (X1, X2, . . . , Xn) is comonotonic. Furthermore, the α-quantile of the sum equals of the sum of the α-quantiles of its components, hence comonotonic random variables are quantile-additive. In practical risk management terms it means that there is minimal (or eventually no) variance reduction from diversification.

For extensions of comonotonicity, see Jouini & Napp (2004) and Puccetti & Scarsini (2010).

Comonotonicity of subsets of Rn

A subset S of Rn is called comonotonic (sometimes also nondecreasing) if, for all (x1, x2, . . . , xn) and (y1, y2, . . . , yn) in S with xi < yi for some i ∈ {1, 2, . . . , n}, it follows that xjyj for all j ∈ {1, 2, . . . , n}.

This means that S is a totally ordered set.

Comonotonicity of probability measures on Rn

Let μ be a probability measure on the n-dimensional Euclidean space Rn and let F denote its multivariate cumulative distribution function, that is

F ( x 1 , , x n ) := μ ( { ( y 1 , , y n ) R n y 1 x 1 , , y n x n } ) , ( x 1 , , x n ) R n .

Furthermore, let F1, . . . , Fn denote the cumulative distribution functions of the n one-dimensional marginal distributions of μ, that means

F i ( x ) := μ ( { ( y 1 , , y n ) R n y i x } ) , x R

for every i ∈ {1, 2, . . . , n}. Then μ is called comonotonic, if

F ( x 1 , , x n ) = min i { 1 , , n } F i ( x i ) , ( x 1 , , x n ) R n .

Note that the probability measure μ is comonotonic if and only if its support S is comonotonic according to the above definition.

Comonotonicity of Rn-valued random vectors

An Rn-valued random vector X = (X1, . . . , Xn) is called comonotonic, if its multivariate distribution (the pushforward measure) is comonotonic, this means

P ( X 1 x 1 , , X n x n ) = min i { 1 , , n } P ( X i x i ) , ( x 1 , , x n ) R n .

Properties

An Rn-valued random vector X = (X1, . . . , Xn) is comonotonic if and only if it can be represented as

( X 1 , , X n ) = d ( F X 1 1 ( U ) , , F X n 1 ( U ) ) ,

where =d stands for equality in distribution, on the right-hand side are the left-continuous generalized inverses of the cumulative distribution functions FX1, . . . , FXn, and U is a uniformly distributed random variable on the unit interval. More generally, a random vector is comonotonic if and only if it agrees in distribution with a random vector where all components are non-decreasing functions (or all are non-increasing functions) of the same random variable.

Upper Fréchet–Hoeffding bound for cumulative distribution functions

Let X = (X1, . . . , Xn) be an Rn-valued random vector. Then, for every i ∈ {1, 2, . . . , n},

P ( X 1 x 1 , , X n x n ) P ( X i x i ) , ( x 1 , , x n ) R n ,

hence

P ( X 1 x 1 , , X n x n ) min i { 1 , , n } P ( X i x i ) , ( x 1 , , x n ) R n ,

with equality everywhere if and only if (X1, . . . , Xn) is comonotonic.

Upper bound for the covariance

Let (X, Y) be a bivariate random vector such that the expected values of X, Y and the product XY exist. Let (X*, Y*) be a comonotonic bivariate random vector with the same one-dimensional marginal distributions as (X, Y). Then it follows from Höffding's formula for the covariance and the upper Fréchet–Hoeffding bound that

Cov ( X , Y ) Cov ( X , Y )

and, correspondingly,

E [ X Y ] E [ X Y ]

with equality if and only if (X, Y) is comonotonic.

Note that this result generalizes the rearrangement inequality and Chebyshev's sum inequality.

References

Comonotonicity Wikipedia